Aliko Dangote, Africa’s wealthiest man, recently signed a multi-billion
dollar contract to build Nigeria’s largest oil refinery, and turn the
oil-rich country into a petroleum exporter. The promise of job creation —
the refinery project is expected to employ 8,000 engineers and create
jobs for 85,000 Nigerians — has excited many commentators. But there are
further reasons for optimism, and lessons for companies looking to
understand the power of indigenous entrepreneurs in emerging markets.
First,
Dangote’s deal is likely to happen. This is not the first time a
multi-billion dollar refinery project has been announced in Nigeria.
Chinese investors have negotiated several infrastructure-for-resources
deals in Nigeria over the past decade. But, despite their history of
success in such deals in other African countries, nothing of substance
has materialized in Nigeria. The latest set of contracts, penned in
2010, have run aground due to haggling over Chinese access to oil blocks
and the threat of unfavorable regulation.
It is not surprising
that China’s success in countries like Angola and Sudan did not
translate to Nigeria. In their research on “Winning in Emerging
Markets“, Harvard professors Tarun Khanna and Krishna Palepu theorize
that emerging economies have unique combinations of institutional voids
(e.g. the absence of market intermediaries or inefficient contract
enforcement mechanisms). Tarun and Palepu suggest that what works in one
country does not necessarily translate to another, and companies have
to repeatedly assess their capabilities and decide whether to:
Replicate or adapt a business model from a different situation
Collaborate with domestic partners or go it alone
Navigate the market’s voids or try to fill them/
For
Chinese companies, the institutional voids in the Nigeria deal include
the complex web of entrenched political interests, and their inability
to navigate it. Lobbyist groups with opposing interests like the
Nigerian fuel importers and the European exporters with which they are
aligned have had more influence on political decisions than Chinese
companies. While countries like Angola also have related issues,
Nigeria’s size and complexity probably would have led the institutional
voids theory to prescribe a different strategy of adaptation and
collaboration. China instead had to deal what economist Raymond Vernon
calls the obsolescing bargain, in the form of post-agreement power grabs
by government agencies.
On the contrary, Khanna’s and Palepu’s
theory would suggest that Dangote, as an insider with political
connections at the highest level, is better positioned to directly fill
the market’s voids and deal with the political risks.
Another
reason for optimism is that Dangote’s move might signal a shift to a
conglomerate-led growth phase in Africa. Clay Christensen’s research
explores interdependent versus modular approaches to customer problems
(pdf). Interdependent systems are well suited to situations where “the
job-to-be-done” is not well understood, or the current solution is not
“good enough”. Modular systems tend to arise after the solution has
become “good enough”, and help the industry participants achieve greater
efficiency. Underdeveloped emerging markets, with their weak
institutions, can be seen as being in the “not good enough” stage. At
this stage, the theory would predict the dominance of interdependent
business groups with strong links to institutions and government. Thus,
transforming the fate of the country’s economy would necessitate pushing
these groups to progressively more complex “jobs”.
This is
exactly what we have seen in fast-growing East Asian economies, where
national business groups like the Korean chaebol or the Japanese
keiretsu have been instrumental in the shift from commodities to
higher-value manufacturing. Samsung started off as a trading company,
evolved to textiles and food processing, and then on to high-value add
manufacturing. Today their business spans electronics, shipbuilding,
construction and aerospace, among many other industries. Samsung’s story
is a microcosm of the Korean growth miracle.
Similarly Dangote’s
business, which has already transformed from a trading company to a
manufacturer of cement and flour, could now be moving into a new phase
of higher value-added products. This step into more complex “jobs” may
also draw other African conglomerates into the mix, and create a
platform for rapid industrialization.
Of course, it can be argued
that Dangote’s move is risky for Nigeria because his success would
concentrate too much power in one man’s hand. This is a valid concern —
the conglomerates of East Asia have had disproportionate power
throughout its growth, and retained significant influence even as the
economies move into modular phases. Samsung alone is still responsible
for a mind-boggling proportion of Korea’s economy. Â African governments
can mitigate this by diversifying contract awards to various national
players, but ultimately it may be a worthy risk for the promise of
growth led by indigenous companies.
No comments:
Post a Comment